Price dispersion in the phenomenon of big data discriminatory pricing (BDDP)

Research Article
Open access

Price dispersion in the phenomenon of big data discriminatory pricing (BDDP)

Yuxuan Qian 1*
  • 1 Jiangnan University    
  • *corresponding author 1089190210@stu.jiangnan.edu.cn
Published on 13 September 2023 | https://doi.org/10.54254/2754-1169/10/20230459
AEMPS Vol.10
ISSN (Print): 2754-1177
ISSN (Online): 2754-1169
ISBN (Print): 978-1-915371-47-8
ISBN (Online): 978-1-915371-48-5

Abstract

Theoretically, competition between firms producing homogeneous products would lead to price convergence. However, there is persistent price dispersion in real markets for homogeneous products. Many scholars have built models from different perspectives to explain the existence of price dispersion in retail markets. Moreover, this price dispersion still exists after entering the Internet era. My paper builds a model based on the phenomenon of many monopolies charging different prices to consumers through big data discriminatory pricing (BDDP) since entering the Internet Big Data era to find price dispersion equilibrium from the perspective of firms. My model adds some variables to a Varian-style model in which consumers are divided into three types and firms charge different prices to maximise profits. Moreover, my study simplifies the actual market situation and is theoretically ideal. It does not perform a multi-stage analysis of consumer switching costs and consideration of consumers entering and leaving the market. However, my paper provides some ideas for subsequent research on price dispersion in Internet monopolies and provides a direction for multi-stage research.

Keywords:

price discrimination, big data discriminatory pricing, Internet price dispersion

Qian,Y. (2023). Price dispersion in the phenomenon of big data discriminatory pricing (BDDP). Advances in Economics, Management and Political Sciences,10,165-170.
Export citation

1. Introduction

Textbook models of competitive markets suggest that competition between firms producing homogeneous products will lead to the so-called "law of one price". However, research from 1961 to the present has shown that price dispersion is constant in many homogeneous product markets. As Hal Varian has argued, "the 'law of one price' is no law at all" [1].

After discovering that the "law of one price" does not last forever, a number of scholars began to study equilibrium with respect to price dispersion. Beginning with Stigler's seminal paper, research on price dispersion has continued to develop [2]. Many scholars have developed models to explain price dispersion as an equilibrium outcome from different perspectives. Most of the classic literature on price dispersion examines the existence of price dispersion in retail markets. Since entering the Internet era, scholars have found that price dispersion still exists. My paper is based on the phenomenon that in the era of Big Data on the Internet, many monopolies charge different prices to consumers through big data discriminatory pricing (BDDP) and will investigate this new phenomenon of price dispersion equilibrium by developing a theoretical model.

A typical example of this phenomenon is Uber and Lyft, two monopoly companies in the online car-hailing industry; the two companies charge higher prices for frequent users through big data. In contrast, new users get very favourable prices, and after more usage, the companies charge consumers higher and higher prices. Another example is Ctrip and Tongcheng, two famous online travelling companies in China; on their platform, consumers will find that the prices of products such as hotel bookings and tickets will continue to rise with increased use. Therefore, based on this phenomenon, my paper will study the price dispersion equilibrium of monopolies to consumers based on big data discriminatory pricing and build a model to find the equilibrium from the firm's perspective.

The two key concepts of my paper are price dispersion and big data discriminatory pricing. The price dispersion here is referred to the price dispersion in the general sense, which means a situation where firms charge different prices in the market for homogeneous products through their strategies. This paper will focus on price dispersion on the Internet. In addition, based on the relevant literature and the current situation of the market, big data discriminatory pricing (BDDP) in this paper refers to platforms and merchants using big data to obtain personal information about consumers' preferences and then raise prices for them when they buy again, making loyal consumers pay higher prices than new consumers. It is also worth mentioning that industries in which big data discriminatory pricing is present essentially have an oligopolistic market structure. Typically, this paper will study price dispersion in Internet monopolies like Uber and Lyft, and build models to find equilibrium by calculating profits from the firm's perspective.

The second part of the paper summarises some of the classic literature on price dispersion and the latest research on Internet price dispersion. Then, this paper develops a Varian-style theoretical model to find its equilibrium prices in the third part. In the fourth part, the researcher concludes the whole paper, clarifies the limitations of the study and makes suggestions for future research. In summary, this paper investigates the phenomenon of price dispersion in Internet monopolies under big data discriminatory pricing and develops a theoretical model to find the equilibrium strategy of the firm.

2. Literature Review

The earliest literature on price dispersion was presented by Stigler [2]. He presented a pioneering model to describe the phenomenon of equilibrium price dispersion and argued that price dispersion is prevalent even for homogeneous goods because of the ignorance of consumers. After Stigler, many scholars have also researched this area and built models to explain price dispersion. Diamond realised that prices might stabilise at purely monopoly prices, and each firm has a monopoly over its loyal customers [3]. The hypothesis of the famous Bargains and Ripoffs paper argued that consumers differ in their ability to make decisions in the marketplace. Rational consumers with a higher ability make informed decisions, while other consumers make uninformed decisions. In the assumption of this paper, consumers differ only in the cost of acquiring information, leading to price dispersion and equilibrium of monopolistic competition [4]. Shilony demonstrated that a firm's stochastic pricing strategy is a mixed equilibrium strategy, and there is no Nash equilibrium for pure pricing strategies [5]. Varian found that most price dispersion models studied spatial price dispersion and temporal price dispersion. He hypothesised that firms attempt to price discriminate between informed and uninformed customers through sales, with uninformed consumers shopping through a randomly selected shop and informed consumers going to the lowest priced shop to make their purchases. Therefore, he explicitly solved the monopolistic competitive equilibrium problem in random pricing strategies [1]. Burdett and Judd's research showed that even if all firms and consumers are ex-ante identical, dispersion in equilibrium prices can occur in the presence of perfectly rational and identical agents on both sides of the market [6]. Stahl believed a two-stage model in which consumers search in perfect recall order. His model considered consumer search friction based on the Varian model [7].

Those mentioned above are some of the classic literatures. As the Internet continues to grow and develop in popularity, some have speculated that Internet markets will eventually show pricing consistent with the textbook "law of one price". However, Baye, Morgan and Scholten found little support for this idea. Their result suggested that, in general, price dispersion on the Internet is a persistent equilibrium phenomenon [8]. In addition, Pan, Ratchford and Shankar have further reviewed the empirical and analytical literature to synthesise the reasons for the existence of price dispersion on the Internet, which may stem from consumer price sensitivity or product differentiation, etc. They argued that online markets are not perfectly competitive, and price dispersion is expected to persist [9]. These researches provide further evidence for the persistence of price dispersion on the Internet.

Based on the above literature review, the researcher can identify the persistence of price dispersion from traditional retail markets to Internet markets. This paper, inspired by the phenomenon of big data discriminatory pricing, will investigate the price dispersion in Internet-type monopolies by developing a theoretical model. The specific modelling and analysis will be shown in the next section.

3. Theoretical Model

The basic framework of the model takes reference from the Varian style model and adds other variables to it in conjunction with big data discriminatory pricing. Suppose there are \( n \) identical firms sell homogeneous goods, and their marginal production cost is defined as \( c \) . There is a unit mass of consumers. Fraction \( λ \) of consumers are old consumers, and fraction \( 1-λ \) of consumers are new consumers. Old consumers are divided into informed consumers \( m \) and uninformed consumers \( λ-m \) .

For informed consumers \( m \) , suppose firms charge them the price \( {p_{i}} \) . Considering consumer switching costs, informed consumers will continue to use the products when the price is between \( {p_{s}} \) and \( {p_{l}} \) ; the difference between \( {p_{l}} \) and \( {p_{s}} \) is the consumers' switching costs. When the price \( {p_{l}} \) is reached, informed consumers will abandon their purchase and switch to another company's product. That is to say, \( {p_{l}} \) is the valuation of old consumers. For uninformed consumers \( λ-m \) , this paper assumes that they are unaware of the existence of big data discriminatory pricing and will continue to purchase products, so a firm can always price discriminate against them and charge them \( {p_{l}} \) , which is the highest price. Finally, for new consumers \( 1-λ \) , suppose firms charge them the price \( {p_{j}} \) . If new consumers appear in the market, the highest price they are charged is \( {p_{s}} \) . That is to say, \( {p_{s}} \) is the valuation of new consumers. Considering \( {p_{s}} \) is the upper bound price of new consumers, and \( {p_{l}} \) is the upper bound price of old consumers. To simplify the model by uniting \( {p_{i}} \) and \( {p_{j}} \) , it is assumed that \( {p_{i}} \) and \( {p_{j}} \) follow the same law of variation and take endpoint values simultaneously.

Some key points about my model need further elaboration. In my model, this paper classifies consumers into three types: informed, uninformed, and new. My model examines a simple initial situation where consumers are assumed to be equally divided among firms with homogeneous products at the very beginning. Profit is calculated from the firm's perspective without considering factors such as consumers who do not enter or leave. In addition, as the study is about price dispersion in a monopolistic industry, this paper assumes that consumers have no search costs, but they switch directly between monopolies.

Moreover, on an actual website, the prices charged by firms should fluctuate within a specific range. However, to simplify the model, this paper assumes that the highest prices charged by firms are denoted by \( {p_{s}} \) and \( {p_{l}} \) respectively, representing a specific range of values. In summary, the model describes the process of new consumers entering the market and firms charging them prices between \( c \) and \( {p_{s}} \) . When the price reaches \( {p_{s}} \) , the new consumers switch to old consumers, divided into informed and uninformed consumers, with informed consumers buying at a price between \( {p_{s}} \) and \( {p_{l}} \) , and uninformed consumers always being charged the highest price \( {p_{l}} \) . This model examines the initial situation in the market, assuming that consumers are equally divided, and does not consider the case of consumers leaving or switching. Profit is calculated from the firm's perspective, where \( {p_{i}} \) and \( {p_{j}} \) are two variables, so the firm's profit is an equation with two unknowns.

Based on the variables set above, this paper then performs a calculation of the firm's profit and finds the equilibrium prices for the model. So, what are the equilibrium prices in this model? First, this paper will prove that there is no pure strategy in this equilibrium. The proof is as follows:

Can \( {p_{i1}} \) =...= \( {p_{in}} \) = \( {p_{j1}} \) =...= \( {p_{jn}} \) = \( c \) be an equilibrium?

The answer is no, because then one firm can deviate by charging \( {p_{j1}} \) = \( {p_{s}} \) . New consumers still buy products from this firm. Therefore its profit is higher than 0.

Can \( {p_{i1}} \) =...= \( {p_{in}} \) = \( {p_{j1}} \) =...= \( {p_{jn}} \) > \( c \) be an equilibrium?

The answer is no, because one firm can deviate by charging \( {p_{i1}} \) = \( {p_{l}}-ε \) retaining departing consumers, where \( ε \) is infinitely small. There is also a profitable deviation.

Can \( {p_{i1}} \) =...= \( {p_{in}} \) > \( c \) , \( {p_{j1}} \) =...= \( {p_{jn}} \) = \( c \) be an equilibrium?

The answer is no, because then one firm can deviate by charging \( {p_{j1}} \) = \( {p_{s}} \) as well.

Can \( {p_{i1}} \) =...= \( {p_{in}} \) = \( c \) , \( {p_{j1}} \) =...= \( {p_{jn}} \) > \( c \) be an equilibrium?

The answer is no, because one firm can deviate by charging \( {p_{j1}} \) = \( {p_{s}}-ε \) as well.

Second, this paper will find the mixed strategy in this equilibrium.

Since the firm charges prices to three types of consumers, where \( {p_{i}} \) and \( {p_{j}} \) are two different variables charged from two different type of consumers, this paper looks at a symmetric equilibrium, in which all firms play mixed strategy \( T({p_{i}},{p_{j}})=F({p_{i}})F({p_{j}}) \) , which means the probability that the firm simultaneously charges informed consumers price \( {p_{i}} \) and new consumers price \( {p_{j}} \) . Note, the support of distribution is \( {(p_{i}}{,p_{j}})∈[({p_{s}},c),({p_{l}},{p_{s}})] \) . The profit of firm 1 is made up of the following components:

The paper supposes each other firm chooses price \( {p_{i}} \) according to \( F({p_{i}}) \) . The probability that firm 1 has a lower price is \( 1-F({p_{i}}) \) . This must hold for all firms. Therefore, the profit from informed consumers is \( m{[1-F({p_{i}})]^{n-1}}({p_{i}}-c) \) .

Since uninformed consumers always buy products from the firm, the firm can always charge them the highest price. This means that the profit from the uninformed consumers equals to \( \frac{λ-m}{n}({p_{l}}-c) \) .

The paper supposes each other firm chooses price \( {p_{j}} \) according to \( F({p_{j}}) \) . Similarly, the probability that firm 1 has a lower price is \( 1-F({p_{j}}) \) . This must hold for all firms. Firms charge prices to new consumers in the interval from \( c \) to \( {p_{s}} \) , so that consumers who leave or do not enter the market are not considered in the calculation. It is assumed that all new consumers enter the market within this interval. Therefore, the profit from new consumers is \( (1-λ){[1-F({p_{j}})]^{n-1}}({p_{j}}-c) \) .

In summary, the total expected profit is

\( {π_{1}}({p_{i}},{p_{j}})=m{[1-F({p_{i}})]^{n-1}}({p_{i}}-c)+\frac{λ-m}{n}({p_{l}}-c) \)

\( +(1-λ){[1-F({p_{j}})]^{n-1}}({p_{j}}-c) \)

Next, this paper needs to find the equilibrium of the model based on this profit formula. The equilibrium of the model is that for any \( {p_{i}} \) and \( {p_{j}} \) , the firm's profit is always the same. That is to say, the key idea is that the expected profit is constant for any \( {p_{i}} \) and \( {p_{j}} \) so the paper solves the problem based on the endpoint values: \( {π_{1}}({p_{i}},{p_{j}})={π_{1}}({p_{l}},{p_{s}}) \) . Note, that \( F({p_{l}})=1 \) and \( F({p_{s}})=1 \) . This paper calculated that:

\( {π_{1}}({p_{l}},{p_{s}})=\frac{λ-m}{n}({p_{l}}-c) \)

\( {π_{1}}({p_{i}},{p_{j}})=m{[1-F({p_{i}})]^{n-1}}({p_{i}}-c)+\frac{λ-m}{n}({p_{l}}-c) \)

\( +(1-λ){[1-F({p_{j}})]^{n-1}}({p_{j}}-c)=\frac{λ-m}{n}({p_{l}}-c) \)

Therefore, the researcher obtains the equation for the relationship between \( {p_{i}} \) and \( {p_{j}} \) .

When \( 0≤F({p_{j}}) \lt 1 \) ,

\( \frac{1-F({p_{i}})}{1-F({p_{j}})}={(\frac{λ-1}{m}\frac{{p_{j}}-c}{{p_{i}}-c})^{\frac{1}{n-1}}} \)

When \( F({p_{j}})=1 \) ,

\( F({p_{i}})=1 \)

From the above definition, it is clear that \( T({p_{i}},{p_{j}})=F({p_{i}})F({p_{j}}) \) .

When \( T(\overline{{p_{i}}},\overline{{p_{j}}})=0 \) , the lower bound support for \( T({p_{i}},{p_{j}}) \) is \( \frac{\overline{{p_{j}}}-c}{\overline{{p_{i}}}-c}=\frac{m}{λ-1} \) , defined as \( (\overline{{p_{i}}},\overline{{p_{j}}}) \) .

When \( T(\overline{{p_{i}}},\overline{{p_{j}}})=1 \) , the upper bound support for \( T({p_{i}},{p_{j}}) \) is \( ({p_{l}},{p_{s}}) \) .

Therefore the support of \( T({p_{i}},{p_{j}})=F({p_{i}})F({p_{j}}) \) is \( [(\overline{{p_{i}}},\overline{{p_{j}}}),({p_{l}},{p_{s}})] \) .

After the above calculations, this paper concludes that firms play a continuous mixed strategy on \( [(\overline{{p_{i}}},\overline{{p_{j}}}),({p_{l}},{p_{s}})] \) , in which \( (\overline{{p_{i}}},\overline{{p_{j}}}) \) obeys the relation of \( \frac{\overline{{p_{j}}}-c}{\overline{{p_{i}}}-c}=\frac{m}{λ-1} \) .

4. Conclusion

My model adds variables to the Varian style model to find an equilibrium strategy of price dispersion for monopolistic Internet companies based on the phenomenon of big data discriminatory pricing. In the case of Internet price discrimination, consumers are divided into three types, and firms charge them different prices to price discriminate and thus maximise profit. My paper investigates the initial situation where consumers are divided equally, finds the Nash equilibrium through critical values and ultimately obtains the firm's mixed equilibrium strategy.

My study simplifies the actual market situation, considers profit from the firm's perspective and does not carry out a multi-stage analysis of consumer switching. In addition, it does not consider consumers who do not enter and leave the market but assumes a perfect situation where the firm does not charge more than the maximum value of the price. However, my paper provides some ideas for subsequent studies on Internet price dispersion, examining a special case of price dispersion equilibrium and providing a direction for multi-stage studies. A possible direction for future research could be to further explore dynamic multi-stage models based on this or to further investigate the existence of consumer switching costs as well as search costs to set up a model.


References

[1]. Varian, Hal R. (1980) A model of sales. The American economic review 70.4: 651-659.

[2]. Stigler, George J. (1961) The economics of information. Journal of political economy 69.3: 213-225.

[3]. Diamond, Peter A. (1971) A model of price adjustment. Journal of economic theory 3.2: 156-168.

[4]. Salop, Steven, and Joseph Stiglitz. (1977) Bargains and ripoffs: A model of monopolistically competitive price dispersion. The Review of Economic Studies 44.3: 493-510.

[5]. Shilony, Yuval. (1977) Mixed pricing in oligopoly. Journal of Economic Theory 14.2: 373-388.

[6]. Burdett, Kenneth, and Kenneth L. Judd. (1983) Equilibrium price dispersion. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society: 955-969.

[7]. Stahl, Dale O. (1989) Oligopolistic pricing with sequential consumer search. The American Economic Review: 700-712.

[8]. Baye, Michael R., John Morgan, and Patrick Scholten. (2004) Price dispersion in the small and in the large: Evidence from an internet price comparison site. The Journal of Industrial Economics 52.4: 463-496.

[9]. Pan, Xing, Brian T. Ratchford, and Venkatesh Shankar. (2004) Price dispersion on the internet: a review and directions for future research. Journal of Interactive marketing 18.4: 116-135.


Cite this article

Qian,Y. (2023). Price dispersion in the phenomenon of big data discriminatory pricing (BDDP). Advances in Economics, Management and Political Sciences,10,165-170.

Data availability

The datasets used and/or analyzed during the current study will be available from the authors upon reasonable request.

Disclaimer/Publisher's Note

The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of EWA Publishing and/or the editor(s). EWA Publishing and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

About volume

Volume title: Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Business and Policy Studies

ISBN:978-1-915371-47-8(Print) / 978-1-915371-48-5(Online)
Editor:Javier Cifuentes-Faura, Canh Thien Dang
Conference website: https://2023.confbps.org/
Conference date: 26 February 2023
Series: Advances in Economics, Management and Political Sciences
Volume number: Vol.10
ISSN:2754-1169(Print) / 2754-1177(Online)

© 2024 by the author(s). Licensee EWA Publishing, Oxford, UK. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license. Authors who publish this series agree to the following terms:
1. Authors retain copyright and grant the series right of first publication with the work simultaneously licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution License that allows others to share the work with an acknowledgment of the work's authorship and initial publication in this series.
2. Authors are able to enter into separate, additional contractual arrangements for the non-exclusive distribution of the series's published version of the work (e.g., post it to an institutional repository or publish it in a book), with an acknowledgment of its initial publication in this series.
3. Authors are permitted and encouraged to post their work online (e.g., in institutional repositories or on their website) prior to and during the submission process, as it can lead to productive exchanges, as well as earlier and greater citation of published work (See Open access policy for details).

References

[1]. Varian, Hal R. (1980) A model of sales. The American economic review 70.4: 651-659.

[2]. Stigler, George J. (1961) The economics of information. Journal of political economy 69.3: 213-225.

[3]. Diamond, Peter A. (1971) A model of price adjustment. Journal of economic theory 3.2: 156-168.

[4]. Salop, Steven, and Joseph Stiglitz. (1977) Bargains and ripoffs: A model of monopolistically competitive price dispersion. The Review of Economic Studies 44.3: 493-510.

[5]. Shilony, Yuval. (1977) Mixed pricing in oligopoly. Journal of Economic Theory 14.2: 373-388.

[6]. Burdett, Kenneth, and Kenneth L. Judd. (1983) Equilibrium price dispersion. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society: 955-969.

[7]. Stahl, Dale O. (1989) Oligopolistic pricing with sequential consumer search. The American Economic Review: 700-712.

[8]. Baye, Michael R., John Morgan, and Patrick Scholten. (2004) Price dispersion in the small and in the large: Evidence from an internet price comparison site. The Journal of Industrial Economics 52.4: 463-496.

[9]. Pan, Xing, Brian T. Ratchford, and Venkatesh Shankar. (2004) Price dispersion on the internet: a review and directions for future research. Journal of Interactive marketing 18.4: 116-135.