1. Introduction
Since the implementation of the minimum wage system following the Reform and Opening-up, it has played a significant and undeniable role in solidly advancing common prosperity. However, income polarization has remained a severe issue in the 21st century. The intensification of income disparities not only suppresses economic growth and entrenches the difficulties faced by low-income groups but also triggers a series of socio-economic problems, such as structural changes in society [1] and hindering the upward mobility of medium-skilled workers [2].
Research on minimum wage policies shows significant differences between domestic and international studies. Abroad, a systematic theoretical framework has been established, primarily focusing on wage effects and employment controversies, with attention to labor market equilibrium [3], technological heterogeneity [4], and firm cost adjustments [5]. In contrast, domestic research is more policy-oriented, concentrating on local issues such as migrant employment and crime [6], employment of people with disabilities [7], and entrepreneurship in the digital economy [8]. Studies on income polarization mainly emphasize its concepts, characteristics, and measurement methods. The ER index, based on the “identity-alienation” framework, measures multi-level polarization by assessing within-group homogeneity and between-group heterogeneity [9]; the W-shaped index divides income groups by the median [10], quantifying the degree of polarization.
Some scholars argue that raising the minimum wage standard exacerbates income polarization. An increase in the minimum wage produces a significant spillover effect on employees earning wages above the minimum wage [11], thereby raising their wage levels and expanding income polarization. Moreover, the minimum wage can reduce employment levels among low-income workers through employment effects, further intensifying income polarization. Conversely, other scholars contend that increasing the minimum wage weakens income polarization. The wage increase creates a truncation effect, elevating the wages of those previously earning below the minimum wage [9], thereby expanding the middle-income group and mitigating income polarization.
Currently, international research mainly focuses on measurement methods and cross-country trends, while domestic studies primarily analyze macro-level trends, with less attention given to decomposition and the impact of minimum wage policies. This paper utilizes county-level data from the China Family Panel Studies (CFPS) spanning 2010 to 2022 and employs the W-shaped polarization index to examine the impact of minimum wage standards on income polarization from a micro-level perspective. The study aims to provide empirical evidence to help alleviate income polarization.
2. Theoretical hypotheses
This paper puts forward the following theoretical hypotheses:
Hypothesis |
Core Mechanism |
Hypothesis 1: The increase in the minimum wage standard exacerbates income polarization. |
The minimum wage increase raises wages of low-income earners through a truncation effect, but spillover effects may also elevate wages of high-income earners; firms reduce employment of low-skilled labor due to higher costs, leading to increased unemployment. |
Hypothesis 2: Total factor productivity (TFP) strengthens the positive impact of the minimum wage on income polarization. |
Skill-biased technological progress. TFP improvements accelerate technological upgrading, causing firms to prefer hiring high-skilled labor [12], further squeezing employment and income opportunities for low-skilled workers. |
Hypothesis 3: Labor factor abundance amplifies the effect of the minimum wage on income polarization. |
When labor supply is abundant, firms are more likely to adjust their employment structure in response to cost pressures, thereby widening income disparities. |
Hypothesis 4: Industrial structure upgrading mediates the widening effect of the minimum wage on income polarization. |
The minimum wage promotes industrial upgrading, increasing high-skilled jobs while pushing out low-skilled labor, thus widening the income gap. |
Based on the theory of structural employment effects, an increase in the minimum wage standard drives industrial transformation by raising labor costs [13]. The rising cost of low-skilled labor leads to the contraction of low value-added industries, reducing the share of primary industries. Meanwhile, wage growth enhances consumption capacity, stimulating demand for high value-added services and promoting the expansion of secondary and tertiary industries [14]. This industrial upgrading reshapes the income distribution pattern: the expansion of high-skilled service sectors creates high-income jobs, while low-skilled workers are forced into informal employment or unemployment, thereby exacerbating income polarization [15].
3. Research design
3.1. Data sources and processing
The income data used in this study are derived from the China Family Panel Studies (CFPS) conducted between 2010 and 2022, while minimum wage data are obtained from official documents issued by the Ministry of Human Resources and Social Security. Data processing includes the exclusion of non-Chinese nationals, samples with missing county-level codes, and samples with missing values in key variables. Additionally, continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers.
3.2. Variable selection and construction
3.2.1. Variable description
The dependent variable in this study is the income polarization index of residents at the county level, primarily calculated based on the "total work income" reported in the adult questionnaire. The income polarization is measured using the W-shaped polarization index proposed by Förster and Wolfson. The minimum wage standard is measured by the natural logarithm of the monthly minimum wage. Control variables are selected with reference to the approach of Zhou Guangsuo et al [16]., focusing mainly on county-level socioeconomic and demographic characteristics.
3.2.2. Model specification
This study constructs the following two-way fixed effects model:
In the model, the dependent variable fw represents the annual Förster & Wolfson index for each county; the independent variable lnwage_standard denotes the natural logarithm of the minimum wage standard for each county and year; C represents the set of control variables; i indicates the region; t denotes the year. δ represents regional fixed effects, θ denotes year fixed effects, and ε is the random error term.
Variable Name |
Variable Symbol |
Dependent Variable |
|
Folster&Wolfson(1992)Index |
fw |
Independent Variable |
|
Natural logarithm of minimum wage standard |
lnwage_standard |
Control Variables |
|
Per capita GDP |
lnmgdp |
Average age |
mean_age |
Average years of education |
mean_edu |
Proportion of male population |
man_proportion |
Household size |
familysize |
Urbanization rate |
urbanizationrate |
4. Empirical analysis
4.1. Descriptive statistics
The mean value of the income polarization index is 0.466, with a standard deviation of 0.188. The mean value of the logarithm of the minimum wage is 7.194, with a standard deviation of 0.344. The values of all variables fall within reasonable ranges.
4.2. Baseline regression results
To test Hypothesis 1, Table 3 reports the regression results of the baseline model (4.2): Column (1) includes neither fixed effects nor control variables; Column (2) includes control variables; Column (3) includes both fixed effects and control variables. The results show that an increase in the minimum wage standard significantly raises the level of income polarization, thereby confirming Hypothesis 1.
(1) |
(2) |
(3) |
|
fw |
fw |
fw |
|
lnwage_standard |
-0.361*** |
0.082 |
1.361*** |
(-5.0832) |
(0.8991) |
(2.7356) |
|
lnmgdp |
-0.272*** |
-0.229* |
|
(-4.4187) |
(-1.6938) |
||
mean_age |
0.023*** |
0.030** |
|
(4.2818) |
(2.3899) |
||
mean_edu |
-0.045** |
0.260*** |
|
(-2.4077) |
(4.3570) |
||
man_proportion |
-0.044 |
-0.217 |
|
(-0.0728) |
(-0.3009) |
||
familysize |
0.021 |
-0.042 |
|
(0.4026) |
(-0.2933) |
||
urbanization_rate |
-0.001 |
0.001 |
|
(-0.4266) |
(0.5559) |
||
Constant |
3.064*** |
2.042*** |
-7.933** |
(5.8952) |
(2.9942) |
(-2.2451) |
|
year fe |
No |
No |
Yes |
city fe |
No |
No |
Yes |
N |
937 |
926 |
926 |
r2_a |
0.031 |
0.161 |
0.343 |
F |
25.839 |
12.621 |
. |
4.3. Regression results of the two-way fixed effects model
As shown in Table 4, after controlling for year and regional fixed effects as well as per capita GDP, the increase in the minimum wage standard still significantly exacerbates income polarization, and the estimated coefficient remains robust.
(1) |
(2) |
|
Variable Name |
Two-Way Fixed Effects |
|
lnwage_standard |
1.265*** (2.55) |
1.139*** (2.38) |
lnmgdp |
YES |
NO |
mean_age |
YES |
YES |
mean_edu |
YES |
YES |
man_proportion |
YES |
YES |
Sample Size |
937 |
937 |
R2 |
0.345 |
0.340 |
Number of Counties and Districts |
162 |
162 |
4.4. Robustness tests
After replacing the polarization index, controlling for provincial fixed effects, and excluding data from 2020, the minimum wage standard continues to significantly promote income polarization, demonstrating the robustness of the conclusions.
4.5. Endogeneity treatment
This study addresses endogeneity by using the average minimum wage standard of other counties and districts within the same city [6] [17] as an instrumental variable. The two-stage least squares (2SLS) results in Table 5 show that the coefficients in both the first and second stage regressions are significantly positive. Additionally, tests reject both the under-identification and weak instrument hypotheses, indicating that the minimum wage standard exacerbates income polarization.
(1) |
(2) |
|
First Stage |
Second Stage |
|
Variable |
lnwage_standard |
fw |
mlowincome |
0.0006*** |
3.2532** |
(39.19) |
(2.50) |
|
Controls |
Yes |
Yes |
Constant |
5.9317*** |
|
(36.20) |
||
Kleibergen-PaaprkLMstatistic |
40.831*** (0.000) |
|
Cragg-DonaldWaldFstatistic |
108.074 (16.380) |
|
N |
936 |
933 |
R-squared |
0.123 |
0.334 |
5. Further analysis
5.1. Mechanism analysis of the minimum wage standard’s effect on income polarization
5.1.1. Moderating effect analysis
5.1.1.1. Total factor productivity
To test Hypothesis 2, this study constructs an interaction term between the minimum wage standard and total factor productivity (TFP) (denoted as TJ_c). The results in Table 6 indicate that total factor productivity significantly strengthens the amplifying effect of the minimum wage on income polarization. Since the employment creation effect of the minimum wage is weaker than its employment erosion effect [18], improvements in total factor productivity reinforce skill-biased technological progress, intensifying the crowding out of low-skilled workers. This positively moderates the minimum wage’s effect on income polarization, thus supporting Hypothesis 2.
5.1.1.2. Labor factor abundance
To test Hypothesis 3, this study constructs an interaction term between the minimum wage standard and labor factor abundance (denoted as TJ2_c). The results in Table 6 demonstrate that labor factor abundance has a positive moderating effect: when labor supply is abundant, firms face greater cost pressures and are more inclined to reduce low-skilled employment, thereby exacerbating income polarization. This supports Hypothesis 3.
(1) |
(2) |
(1) |
(2) |
|
Variable |
Model 1 |
Model 2 |
Model 1 |
Model 2 |
lnwage_standard |
0.4280*** |
0.4118*** |
0.4655*** |
0.3042*** |
(0.1017) |
(0.1021) |
(0.1032) |
(0.1116) |
|
TFP |
3.5922*** |
3.8112*** |
||
(0.8468) |
(0.8556) |
|||
labour_rate |
0.0246*** |
0.0392*** |
||
(0.0054) |
(0.0067) |
|||
TJ_c |
1.0820* |
|||
(0.6383) |
||||
TJ2_c |
0.0388*** |
|||
(0.0106) |
||||
Controls |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Constant |
0.0174 |
-0.1600 |
0.7229 |
0.8306 |
(1.1842) |
(1.1873) |
(1.0708) |
(1.0627) |
|
N |
936 |
936 |
936 |
936 |
adj.R2 |
0.0520 |
0.0543 |
0.0551 |
0.0700 |
5.1.2. Mediation effect analysis
Based on Hypothesis 4, this study conducts an empirical analysis using a mediation effect model, constructing the following models.
Where Medi,t is the mediating variable.
This study uses the industrial structure advancement index (IND) as the mediating variable [19]. This index is calculated by weighting the value added of the three economic sectors, with higher values indicating a more advanced industrial structure. The results in Table 7 show that industrial structure upgrading plays a significant mediating role. The increase in the minimum wage promotes industrial upgrading, while the accompanying skill-biased technological progress crowds out low-skilled labor [15], thereby exacerbating income polarization. Hypothesis 4 is thus supported.
(1) |
(2) |
|
fw |
IND |
|
lnwage_standard |
1.265*** |
1.670*** |
(0.474) |
(0.267) |
|
Controls |
Yes |
Yes |
Constant |
-9.541** |
-1.689 |
(3.770) |
(1.936) |
|
N |
933 |
933 |
5.2. Heterogeneity analysis
The impact of the minimum wage standard on income polarization varies across regions with different income levels. In counties with lower per capita income, the minimum wage standard has a significantly positive effect on income polarization, whereas in counties with higher per capita income, the effect is not significant. This is because enterprises in low-income counties have weaker risk resilience and are more likely to reduce wages or positions for low-skilled workers when the minimum wage rises, directly impacting the income of low-income groups and exacerbating polarization effects.
6. Research conclusions and policy recommendations
6.1. Research conclusions
This study finds that: (1) increases in the minimum wage standard significantly exacerbate income polarization, a conclusion supported by robustness and endogeneity tests; (2) the underlying mechanisms operate primarily through total factor productivity, labor factor abundance, and the level of industrial structure; and (3) this effect exhibits income heterogeneity, being particularly pronounced in low-income regions.
6.2. Policy recommendations
This paper proposes the following policy recommendations: First, implement differentiated minimum wage adjustment strategies—moderate the pace of adjustment in labor-intensive regions, while reasonably adjusting in capital- and technology-intensive regions in line with productivity growth. Second, provide targeted support policies for groups such as farmers, aiming to reduce burdens and increase incomes to narrow income disparities. Third, strengthen coordinated regional development by leveraging opportunities from industrial relocation to optimize the industrial structure in underdeveloped areas and enhance regional linkage and development.
References
[1]. He, R. L. (2021). China’s experience in polarization governance. Beijing, China: Renmin University Press.
[2]. Feng, Y. W. (2020). The emergence, measurement, and impact of wage polarization. Contemporary Economics, (12), 105–107.
[3]. Stigler, G. J. (1946). The economics of minimum wage legislation. The American Economic Review, 36, 358–365.
[4]. Heckman, J., & Sedlacek, G. (1981). The impact of the minimum wage on the employment and earnings of workers in South Carolina. Report of the Minimum Wage Study Commission, 5, 225–272.
[5]. Acharya, V. V., Baghai, R. P., & Subramanian, K. V. (2013). Labor laws and innovation. The Journal of Law & Economics, 56, 997–1037.
[6]. Zhang, D. D., Li, L. X., & Tong, C. (2018). Minimum wage, migrant unemployment, and crime. Economics (Quarterly), 17(03), 1035–1054.
[7]. Zhang, Q., Feng, S. L., & Cao, H. (2022). Minimum wage adjustment and employment of people with disabilities in China: Empirical evidence and mechanisms based on county-level matched pairs and individual tracking data. Economics (Quarterly), 22(03), 1061–1078.
[8]. Liu, S. L., & Ma, S. (2025). Minimum wage and digital entrepreneurship: A demand creation perspective. Economic Dynamics, (03), 128–145.
[9]. Esteban, J.-M., & Ray, D. (1994). On the measurement of polarization. Econometrica, 62(4), 819–851.
[10]. Wolfson, M. C. (1994). When inequalities diverge. The American Economic Review, 84, 353–358.
[11]. Yin, Y. H., & Sun, X. D. (2023). How do artificial intelligence and capital taxes affect income distribution patterns: Polarization or optimization? Journal of Shenzhen University (Humanities and Social Sciences Edition), 40(01), 83–91.
[12]. Zhang, Y., & Li, H. J. (2022). The impact of enterprise intelligent transformation on internal labor structure adjustment. China Human Resources Development, 39(01), 98–118.
[13]. Zheng, X. W., Wang, D. D., & Zhang, Y. (2020). Minimum wage standards, government innovation intervention, and urban industrial structure upgrading: Empirical evidence from 279 prefecture-level cities in China. East China Economic Management, 34(12), 39–47.
[14]. Wu, Y. M. (2017). The industrial structure effect of China’s minimum wage system [Master’s thesis, Guangdong University of Foreign Studies].
[15]. Autor, D. H., Katz, L. F., & Kearney, M. S. (2006). The polarization of the U.S. labor market. The American Economic Review, 96(2), 189–194.
[16]. Zhou, G. S., Ding, X. Y., & Zhang, W. H. (2023). Minimum wage standards, resident income inequality, and common prosperity: Analysis based on CFPS panel data. Economic Issues Exploration, (10), 31–47.
[17]. Cui, X. M., Yu, M. J., & Yuan, D. (2018). Minimum wage and domestic value-added in exports: Evidence from Chinese firms. World Economy, 41(12), 49–72.
[18]. Lu, X. B. (2016). The impact of China’s minimum wage on labor market supply [Master’s thesis, Wuhan University].
[19]. Sun, W. Z., Niu, D. X., & Wan, G. H. (2022). Transportation infrastructure construction and industrial structure upgrading: An empirical analysis based on high-speed rail construction. Management World, 38(03), 19–34+58+35–41.
Cite this article
Jin,W. (2025). Does the Minimum Wage Standard Weaken Income Polarization?. Advances in Economics, Management and Political Sciences,205,42-51.
Data availability
The datasets used and/or analyzed during the current study will be available from the authors upon reasonable request.
Disclaimer/Publisher's Note
The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of EWA Publishing and/or the editor(s). EWA Publishing and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.
About volume
Volume title: Proceedings of ICEMGD 2025 Symposium: The 4th International Conference on Applied Economics and Policy Studies
© 2024 by the author(s). Licensee EWA Publishing, Oxford, UK. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and
conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license. Authors who
publish this series agree to the following terms:
1. Authors retain copyright and grant the series right of first publication with the work simultaneously licensed under a Creative Commons
Attribution License that allows others to share the work with an acknowledgment of the work's authorship and initial publication in this
series.
2. Authors are able to enter into separate, additional contractual arrangements for the non-exclusive distribution of the series's published
version of the work (e.g., post it to an institutional repository or publish it in a book), with an acknowledgment of its initial
publication in this series.
3. Authors are permitted and encouraged to post their work online (e.g., in institutional repositories or on their website) prior to and
during the submission process, as it can lead to productive exchanges, as well as earlier and greater citation of published work (See
Open access policy for details).
References
[1]. He, R. L. (2021). China’s experience in polarization governance. Beijing, China: Renmin University Press.
[2]. Feng, Y. W. (2020). The emergence, measurement, and impact of wage polarization. Contemporary Economics, (12), 105–107.
[3]. Stigler, G. J. (1946). The economics of minimum wage legislation. The American Economic Review, 36, 358–365.
[4]. Heckman, J., & Sedlacek, G. (1981). The impact of the minimum wage on the employment and earnings of workers in South Carolina. Report of the Minimum Wage Study Commission, 5, 225–272.
[5]. Acharya, V. V., Baghai, R. P., & Subramanian, K. V. (2013). Labor laws and innovation. The Journal of Law & Economics, 56, 997–1037.
[6]. Zhang, D. D., Li, L. X., & Tong, C. (2018). Minimum wage, migrant unemployment, and crime. Economics (Quarterly), 17(03), 1035–1054.
[7]. Zhang, Q., Feng, S. L., & Cao, H. (2022). Minimum wage adjustment and employment of people with disabilities in China: Empirical evidence and mechanisms based on county-level matched pairs and individual tracking data. Economics (Quarterly), 22(03), 1061–1078.
[8]. Liu, S. L., & Ma, S. (2025). Minimum wage and digital entrepreneurship: A demand creation perspective. Economic Dynamics, (03), 128–145.
[9]. Esteban, J.-M., & Ray, D. (1994). On the measurement of polarization. Econometrica, 62(4), 819–851.
[10]. Wolfson, M. C. (1994). When inequalities diverge. The American Economic Review, 84, 353–358.
[11]. Yin, Y. H., & Sun, X. D. (2023). How do artificial intelligence and capital taxes affect income distribution patterns: Polarization or optimization? Journal of Shenzhen University (Humanities and Social Sciences Edition), 40(01), 83–91.
[12]. Zhang, Y., & Li, H. J. (2022). The impact of enterprise intelligent transformation on internal labor structure adjustment. China Human Resources Development, 39(01), 98–118.
[13]. Zheng, X. W., Wang, D. D., & Zhang, Y. (2020). Minimum wage standards, government innovation intervention, and urban industrial structure upgrading: Empirical evidence from 279 prefecture-level cities in China. East China Economic Management, 34(12), 39–47.
[14]. Wu, Y. M. (2017). The industrial structure effect of China’s minimum wage system [Master’s thesis, Guangdong University of Foreign Studies].
[15]. Autor, D. H., Katz, L. F., & Kearney, M. S. (2006). The polarization of the U.S. labor market. The American Economic Review, 96(2), 189–194.
[16]. Zhou, G. S., Ding, X. Y., & Zhang, W. H. (2023). Minimum wage standards, resident income inequality, and common prosperity: Analysis based on CFPS panel data. Economic Issues Exploration, (10), 31–47.
[17]. Cui, X. M., Yu, M. J., & Yuan, D. (2018). Minimum wage and domestic value-added in exports: Evidence from Chinese firms. World Economy, 41(12), 49–72.
[18]. Lu, X. B. (2016). The impact of China’s minimum wage on labor market supply [Master’s thesis, Wuhan University].
[19]. Sun, W. Z., Niu, D. X., & Wan, G. H. (2022). Transportation infrastructure construction and industrial structure upgrading: An empirical analysis based on high-speed rail construction. Management World, 38(03), 19–34+58+35–41.