1. Introduction
In 2019, a burst of Coronavirus was firstly reported from China. Soon, this pandemic swept over 200 countries and territories, and millions of people were infected [4]. Due to the susceptibility to infection and high mortality of this disease, lots of industries such as tourism, manufacture, and various types of services were forced to shut down [6]. It is not only a global health shock, but it also a global economics crisis [9]. So far till 2022, the most severe pandemic period has been come through, and people find that wearing masks can greatly prevent getting infected in pandemic [8]. Most countries have already cancelled the order of lockdown, and people are allowed to work or socialize with mask on.
However, it is common to find number of people refuse to wear masks in public, even though they are awarded of those policies can reduce the probability of infection and the fact that the pandemic has not fully ended [10]. Taking the perspective of evolutionary game theory and public goods game, we categorize this group of people as free riders [2], since they enjoy the relative virus-free environment without contributing any commitment to maintain common safety [3 & 7].
In the current paper, we interpret this non-compliance behavior through the matrix model. In addition, we take the probability of getting infected on condition of wearing masks or not into account when we compute the expected payoff of players. In doing so, we hope to provide the intuition of non-compliance behavior in a different point of view and help to find more possible insights and mechanism for Covid-19 pandemic regulation management.
2. Model
2.1. Introduction and Assumptions
In the current paper, we construct simple game theory model and calculate each player’s expected payoff in the game as the number of players increasing. To establish the model, relevant statistics and assumptions are necessary to clarify.
1.If player has a positive Covid-19 test result, he or she receives (-a) payoff, and if player has a negative Covid-19 test result, he or she receives zero payoff.
2.Mask wearers will receive (-b) payoff due to the uncomfortable experience of wearing masks, and non-mask wearers will receive the payoff of (+b) multiplied by the probability of stay healthy.
3.According to the research conducted by Alihsan et al. on July 31, 2022 [1], the results concluded that in general cases, mask wearers infected by Covid-19 with a probability of 7% and non-mask wearers infected by Covid-19 with probability of 52%.
4.According to the statistical analysis conducted by Ghorbani et al. on June 28 [5], 2021, the result suggested that the probability for people who have been infected by Covid-19 before to get reinfection is about 21%. Therefore, we assume that for them, the probability for them to reinfect by the virus is 0.21 if they do not wear masks. If they wear mask, the probability to reinfect will be 0.01, due to the double protection from masks and antibiotics.
5.We assume that the infection between individuals is independent.
6.We will save three decimal places for statistics.
2.2. Multi-player Infection Model
To derive our multi-player infection model, we start from the simple 2*2 payoff matrix. Based on statistics and assumptions that we established above, we can calculate the expect payoffs of player’s different choices.
\( E(wear masks)=[1 – (1 – 0.07)]*(–a) – b= –0.07a – b \) (1)
\( E(not wear masks)=[1 – (1 – 0.52)]*(–a)+b(1 –0.52)= – 0.52a+0.48 \) (2)
Table 1: 2*2 payoff matrix.
Choice | Wear masks | Not wear masks |
Wear masks | (-0.07a – b), (-0.07a – b) | (-0.07a – b), (-0.52a + 0.48b) |
Not wear masks | (-0.52a + 0.48b), (-0.07a – b) | (-0.52a + 0.48b), (-0.52a + 0.48b) |
The 2*2 payoff matrix exhibits the interaction of two players and the payoff each choice. According to our last assumption that the infection between individuals is independent, in the model of n players, an individual will repeat n times this payoff matrix when he or she interact with other players. Therefore, we can derive the expected payoff of different choices in multi-player infection model.
\( E(wear mask) = [1 – {(1 – 0.07)^{n – 1}} ]*( –a) – b \) (3)
\( E(not wear mask)=[1 – {(1 – 0.52)^{n – 1}}]*( –a)+ b{(1 – 0.52)^{n – 1}} \) (4)
Intuitively, when the expected payoff of not wearing masks exceeds that of wearing masks, players will choose not to wear masks. Based on this basic rule, we can set an inequality to obtain the relationship between the ratio of a and b and players’ decision-making.
\( E(wear mask) \lt E(not wear mask) \)
\( [1-{(1-0.07)^{n-1}}]*(-a)-b \lt [1-{(1-0.52)^{n-1}}]*(-a)+b{(1-0.52)^{n-1}} \) (5)
let \( {(1 – 0.07)^{n – 1}}=x \) ; \( {(1– 0.52)^{n – 1}}= y \)
\( (1 – x)*( –a) – b \lt (1 – y)*( –a)+b*y \) (6)
\( a / b \lt (1 + y) / (x – y) \) (7)
\( a / b \lt [1 + {(0.48)^{n – 1}}] / [{(0.93)^{n – 1}}-{(0.48)^{n – 1}}] \) (8)
Therefore, once a/b ratio is smaller than \( [1 + {(0.48)^{n - 1}}] / [{(0.93)^{n - 1}} - {(0.48)^{n - 1}}] \) , players will choose to not wear masks. We denote a/b ratio that is equal to \( [1 + {(0.48)^{n - 1}}] / [{(0.93)^{n - 1}} - {(0.48)^{n - 1}}] \) as indifference ratio, because at that time, players are indifferent of acting different choices. The following table present the indifference ratio of a/b as n increasing from 2 to 7.
Table 2: Value of a/b as n increasing from 2 to 7.
n | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 |
a/b | 3.289 | 1.930 | 1.601 | 1.515 | 1.530 | 1.595 |
2.3. Multi-player Infection Model of Reinfection
In the study conducted by Ghorbani et al. and assumption, we have established that the probability for them to reinfect by the virus is 0.21 if they do not wear masks. If they wear mask, the probability to reinfect will be 0.01. Then, repeating the previous calculation, we can obtain:
\( E(wear mask) = [1 – {(1 – 0.01)^{n – 1}} ]*( –a) – b \) (9)
\( E(not wear mask) = [1 – {(1 – 0.52)^{n – 1}} ]*( –a)+ b{(1 – 0.52)^{n – 1}} \) (10)
Let \( E(wear mask) \lt E(not wear mask) \)
\( a / b \lt [1 + {(0.79)^{n - 1}}] / [{(0.99)^{n - 1}} - {(0.79)^{n - 1}}] \) (11)
Similarly, we can create a table of the change of a/b indifference ratio of as n increasing.
Table 3: New value of a/b as n increasing from 2 to 7.
n | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 |
a/b | 8.95 | 4.562 | 3.128 | 2.433 | 2.033 | 1.780 |
3. Discussion
As we presented in assumptions, a is the payoff of people who do not wear masks and get infected by Covid-19. To be more specific, a can be considered as the risk of being non-mask wearers. b stands for the payoff of wearing masks. a/b represents the ratio of the risk of not wearing masks and the payoff of wearing masks. Typically, we expect the value of this ratio to be small: lower risk of not wearing on numerator and (or) higher payoff of wearing masks on denominator.
In the Multi-player Infection Model, connecting the ratio of a and b with the decision-making of people in the game, we find a critical point which we denote as the indifferent ratio of a and b. When a/b is equal to this indifferent ratio, players will be indifferent between wearing masks and not wearing masks. Accordingly, when the actual a/b is smaller than the indifferent ratio, people will choose not to wear masks, vice versa.
From the further analysis in Multi-player Infection Model, we know that the indifference ratio of a/b is determined by a function of n, where n is the number of players in the game. As we represented in the model with a table of n increasing from 2 to 7, we observe that the value of indifferent ratio of a/b decreases first and then increases. If we illustrate the deviation of indifferent ratio as n increasing on a graph, we can see a concave-up shape of curve. The intuition behind this shape is that theoretically, the higher population density, the higher risk of Covid-19 infection [11]. As the number of people in the model increases, the probability and risk of an individual to infection increases as well. When n achieve certain amount, the increment rate of risk on numerator will exceed the increment rate of wearing masks on denominator. Then, the curve will exhibit an upward-sloping trend.
We also derive the Multi-player Infection Model for people who have been recovered from Covid-19. Since this group of people have lower probability of reinfection if they do not wear masks and nearly zero probability of reinfection if they wear masks, with all else set equal, they will have a higher indifference ratio compared with standard players. This means that the chance that their indifference ratio higher than the actual a/b will be greater than that of standard players, leading them to choose not to wear masks with higher probability.
4. Conclusion
To sum up, the effectiveness and importance of wearing masks to prevent Covid-19 infection have been proved. Consequently, it is beneficial for governments to strengthen policies in epidemic management. They can issue policies and public announcements to reduce the number of people gathering as much as possible, to avoid the increase in the risk of infection caused by the large number of people. At the same time, people are still advised to wear masks. In the Multi-player Infection Model, it presents that for people who have been recovered from Covid-19, their infection probability is small even though they choose not to wear masks. So, for these group of people, they are not necessary to wear masks in where the number of people around them are relatively small and enjoy the comfortability of not wearing masks. However, it is still recommended for them to wear masks when they are surrounded by large number of people.
Several countries around the world have well shown how to contain the outbreak and reduce the risk. Take China as an example. China’s Covid-19 regulation managements, for example people are compulsory to wear masks in public, are effective. Therefore, if human want to reduce the new cases or eliminate Covid-19 pandemic, more effective policies and the cooperation of masses are needed. The current paper is not only helpful for governments to establish effective pandemic regulation management, but it also provides suggestions to people’s decision-making of wearing masks under Covid-19 pandemic.
References
[1]. Alisan, B., Mohammed, A., Bisen, Y., Lester, J., Nouryan, C.: The Efficacy of Facemasks in the Prevention of COVID-19: A Systematic Review. MedReiv (2022).
[2]. Brune, M. & Wilson, D.R.: Evolutionary perspective on human behavior during the coronavirus pandemic: Insights from game theory. Evolution, Medicine, and Public Health, Volume 2020, Issue 1, 2020, Pages 181-186 (2021).
[3]. Cato, S., Iida, T., Ishida, K., Ito, A., McElwain, K. M., and Shoji, M.: Social distancing as a public good under the COVID-19 pandemic. Public Health 188, 51–53 (2020).
[4]. Craighead, C.W., Ketchen Jr. D.J., and Darby, J.B.: Pandemics and Supply Chain Management Research: Toward a Theoretical Toolbox*. Decision Sciences. Volume 51, Number 4, Pages 838-866 (2020).
[5]. Ghorbani, S.S., Taherpour, N., Bayat, S., Ghajari, H., Mohseni, P., Nazari, S.S.H.: Epidemiologic characteristics of cases with reinfection, recurrence, and hospital readmission due to COVID‐19: A systematic review and meta‐analysis. Journal of Medical Virology. J Med Virol. 2022;94:44–53 (2021).
[6]. Greenway, D. & Nelson, D.: COVID-19, Trade and Trade Policy. World Econ. 2022; 45:338-341, Pages 338-341 (2021).
[7]. Paakkari, L., and Okan, O.: COVID-19: health literacy is an underestimated problem. Lancet Public Health 5, e249–e250 (2020).
[8]. Sugimura, M., Chimed-Ochir, O., Yumiya, Y., Ohge, H., Shime, N., Sakaguichi, T., Tanaka, Junko, Takafuta, T., Mimori, M., Kuwabara, M., Asahara, T., Kishita, E., Kubo, T.: The Association betweenWearing a Mask and COVID-19. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2021, 18, 9131 (2021).
[9]. Vidya, C.T. & Prabheesh, K.P.: Implications of COVID-19 Pandemic on the Global Trade Networks. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 56:10. 2408-2421 (2020).
[10]. Yong, J.C. & Choy, B.C.K.: Noncompliance with Safety Guidelines as a Free-Riding Strategy: An Evolutionary Game-Theoretic Approach to Cooperation During the COVID-19 Pandemic. Front. Psychol. 12:646892 (2021).
[11]. Yin H, Sun T, Yao L, Jiao Y, Ma L, Lin L, Graff JC, Aleya L, Postlethwaite A, Gu W, Chen H. Association between population density and infection rate suggests the importance of social distancing and travel restriction in reducing the COVID-19 pandemic. Environ Sci Pollut Res Int. Aug;28(30):40424-40430. (2021)
Cite this article
Zhang,Y. (2023). Analysis of the Advantages and Disadvantages of People Wearing Masks in COVID-19 Pandemic: A Game-theoretic Approach. Advances in Economics, Management and Political Sciences,14,7-11.
Data availability
The datasets used and/or analyzed during the current study will be available from the authors upon reasonable request.
Disclaimer/Publisher's Note
The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of EWA Publishing and/or the editor(s). EWA Publishing and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.
About volume
Volume title: Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Business and Policy Studies
© 2024 by the author(s). Licensee EWA Publishing, Oxford, UK. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and
conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license. Authors who
publish this series agree to the following terms:
1. Authors retain copyright and grant the series right of first publication with the work simultaneously licensed under a Creative Commons
Attribution License that allows others to share the work with an acknowledgment of the work's authorship and initial publication in this
series.
2. Authors are able to enter into separate, additional contractual arrangements for the non-exclusive distribution of the series's published
version of the work (e.g., post it to an institutional repository or publish it in a book), with an acknowledgment of its initial
publication in this series.
3. Authors are permitted and encouraged to post their work online (e.g., in institutional repositories or on their website) prior to and
during the submission process, as it can lead to productive exchanges, as well as earlier and greater citation of published work (See
Open access policy for details).
References
[1]. Alisan, B., Mohammed, A., Bisen, Y., Lester, J., Nouryan, C.: The Efficacy of Facemasks in the Prevention of COVID-19: A Systematic Review. MedReiv (2022).
[2]. Brune, M. & Wilson, D.R.: Evolutionary perspective on human behavior during the coronavirus pandemic: Insights from game theory. Evolution, Medicine, and Public Health, Volume 2020, Issue 1, 2020, Pages 181-186 (2021).
[3]. Cato, S., Iida, T., Ishida, K., Ito, A., McElwain, K. M., and Shoji, M.: Social distancing as a public good under the COVID-19 pandemic. Public Health 188, 51–53 (2020).
[4]. Craighead, C.W., Ketchen Jr. D.J., and Darby, J.B.: Pandemics and Supply Chain Management Research: Toward a Theoretical Toolbox*. Decision Sciences. Volume 51, Number 4, Pages 838-866 (2020).
[5]. Ghorbani, S.S., Taherpour, N., Bayat, S., Ghajari, H., Mohseni, P., Nazari, S.S.H.: Epidemiologic characteristics of cases with reinfection, recurrence, and hospital readmission due to COVID‐19: A systematic review and meta‐analysis. Journal of Medical Virology. J Med Virol. 2022;94:44–53 (2021).
[6]. Greenway, D. & Nelson, D.: COVID-19, Trade and Trade Policy. World Econ. 2022; 45:338-341, Pages 338-341 (2021).
[7]. Paakkari, L., and Okan, O.: COVID-19: health literacy is an underestimated problem. Lancet Public Health 5, e249–e250 (2020).
[8]. Sugimura, M., Chimed-Ochir, O., Yumiya, Y., Ohge, H., Shime, N., Sakaguichi, T., Tanaka, Junko, Takafuta, T., Mimori, M., Kuwabara, M., Asahara, T., Kishita, E., Kubo, T.: The Association betweenWearing a Mask and COVID-19. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2021, 18, 9131 (2021).
[9]. Vidya, C.T. & Prabheesh, K.P.: Implications of COVID-19 Pandemic on the Global Trade Networks. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 56:10. 2408-2421 (2020).
[10]. Yong, J.C. & Choy, B.C.K.: Noncompliance with Safety Guidelines as a Free-Riding Strategy: An Evolutionary Game-Theoretic Approach to Cooperation During the COVID-19 Pandemic. Front. Psychol. 12:646892 (2021).
[11]. Yin H, Sun T, Yao L, Jiao Y, Ma L, Lin L, Graff JC, Aleya L, Postlethwaite A, Gu W, Chen H. Association between population density and infection rate suggests the importance of social distancing and travel restriction in reducing the COVID-19 pandemic. Environ Sci Pollut Res Int. Aug;28(30):40424-40430. (2021)